Av en slump hade jag möjlighet att träffa en väldigt trevlig individ på en arbetsplats för någon vecka sedan. Individ heter från och med nu "Pär". Mitt i ett samtal med Pär rusade en kvinnlig kollega till Pär in och frågade om han fått aktierna han tecknat?
När den kvinnliga kollegan gick ut frågade jag Pär om han var intresserad av aktier, vilket han visade sig vara. Uppenbarligen hade Pär insett att teckna man aktier inför en notering så gick de i regel upp och det var därför han gillade att teckna aktier. Pär berättade även om hur han satt och hoppades att marknaden skulle falla kraftigt när Trump valdes för då skulle han kunna gå in och köpa "billigt".
Uppenbarligen har Pär hittat en fungerande strategi och beviset för att denna strategin fungerar finnes här, eller som en placerare beskrev det:
"the pattern of fading a potential crisis and then scrambling to cover and get long when everyone takes a breath and realizes that this time not the apocalypse either still holds more than ever. I can’t justify any of this. The lesson investors and traders are getting is that everything is a buying opportunity and you need to not miss the boat. Brexit? Bullish. Trump winning the election? Bullish. Italy saying no to the referendum and the Prime Minister handing in his resignation? Bullish. Heck, all we need is a coup d’etat in India and the entire Belgian banking system to go kablooey and the S&P 500 will be at 3,000 by Christmas Eve" (här)
Jag har tidigare skrivit om William White här och han är en av få större ekonomiska tänkare. William White och hans kollegor gav kraftfulla varningar angående ekonomin under Greenspanns välde. Riskerna White talar om är inte negligerbara, vilket kan ses på den amerikanska fastighetsmarknaden där priserna nått samma nivåer eller högre (justerat för inflationen) som 2005. Om man föredrar att läsa William Whites artikel i sin helhet finnes den här.
"The global situation we face today is arguably more
fraught with danger than was the case when the crisis
first began. By encouraging still more credit and debt
expansion, monetary policy has ‘‘dug the hole deeper.’’
The fundamental analytical mistake has been to model
the economy as an understandable and controllable
machine rather than as a complex, adaptive system.
This mistake also implies that the suggestion that
central banks should necessarily reduce the ‘‘financial
rate of interest,’’ in response to a presumed fall in the
‘‘natural rate,’’ is overly simplistic. In practice, ultraeasy
policy has not stimulated aggregate demand to the
degree expected but has had other unexpected consequences.
Not least, it poses a threat to financial stability
and to potential growth going forward. Further,
‘‘exit’’ threatens to be delayed in many countries,
underlining the dangerous fact that the global economy
has no nominal anchor. Much better would be policies,
introduced by other arms of government, that would
recognize that the fundamental problem is not inadequate
liquidity but excessive debt and possible insolvencies.
The policy stakes are now very high.
(...)In this presentation I will try to trace the origins of
the crisis, and the particular contribution made by
expansionary monetary policies before (unnaturally
easy) and after (ultra-easy) the crisis broke. I will contend that the situation we face in late 2016, both in
the advanced market economies (AMEs) and the
emerging market economies (EMEs), is arguably
more fraught with danger than was the case when the
crisis first began. By encouraging still more credit and
debt expansion, monetary policy has dug the hole still
deeper.
(...)The fundamental
ontological error has been to model the
economy as a relatively simple machine, whose
properties can thus be known and controlled by its
policy operator. In reality, it is an evolving system,
too complex to be either well understood or closely
controlled. Moreover, it is a system in which stocks
and ‘‘imbalances’’ build up over time in response to
monetary stimulus. This reality makes future prospects
totally path dependent, and we are on a bad
path.
(...)How did we get into this mess? I want to suggest that
monetary policy, guided by flawed theory, has played
a big role even if other agents also contributed
materially. The flawed theory is, essentially, that
growth and job creation deemed to be inadequate are
solely due to inadequate demand and that this can
always be remedied with expansionary monetary
policy. Moreover, it is assumed that such policies do
not have significant undesirable side effects. They are,
therefore, the proverbial ‘‘free lunch.’
(...)In short, in the aftermath of the crisis, ultra-easy
monetary policy soon became ‘‘the only game in
town.’’ Unfortunately, monetary policy shares the
shortcoming of all the other policies. Its effectiveness
decreases over time, while its negative side effects
increase over time.
(...)These are not just theoretical considerations. The
BIS Annual Report of 2014 sounded the alarm when it
noted that the level of debt in the AMEs (sum of
corporate, household, and governments) was then
significantly higher than it had been in 2007. Moreover,
it has since risen further, to over 260 percent of
GDP. This increase has prompted the question
‘‘Deleveraging? What deleveraging?’’ This suggests
that, by following polices that have actively discouraged
deleveraging, we may instead have set ourselves
up for an even more serious crisis in the future.
(...)There are clearly grounds for believing that monetary
policy, both before and since the crisis, has contributed
to a reduction in the level of potential or even
its growth rate. In fact, both seem to have declined
sharply in AMEs in recent years. As Schumpeter
might have put it, without destruction there can be no
creation. It is a fact that in many countries, the entry of
new firms and the exit of old ones has been on a
declining trend. Worse, if easy money actually lowers
potential growth, and this induces still more easy
money, the possibility of a vicious downward spiral is
clear.
(...)Moreover, as perceptions changed as to
whether monetary policy would be effective or not,
market reactions have bifurcated. When the mood is
positive, financing flows (Risk On) to more risky
assets, and when the mood is negative the opposite
occurs (Risk Off). This focus of RORO investors,
essentially on tail risks, seriously reduces the longerrun
benefits of diversification and of value investing
(...)As of mid-2016, we observed
record high equity prices, record low (even negative)
bond yields for ‘‘riskless’’ assets, high-yield spreads
back down from February levels, record low costs of
cover (e.g.: the Vix), the return of cov-lite and Payment
in Kind (PIK) financing, and a general lowering
of lending standards. Broadly speaking, the levels of
prices in financial markets today look as stretched as
they did in 2007 just before the crisis erupted
(...)4. The Need for ‘‘Exit’’ and Possible End
Games
Simple uncertainty about the full effects (not only
unexpected but potentially undesirable) of today’s
radical monetary policies might, in itself, seem to
argue powerfully for their moderation What has been
done is totally unprecedented and totally experimental. But there is another no less powerful argument
for eventual exit. If the effects on aggregate demand
decline with time, while the undesired side effects
cumulate with time, at some point these two functions
must intersect. At that point, monetary policy would
have to be judged to be doing more harm than good.
At this due date, ‘‘exit’’ would then be warranted.
Finally, and more in keeping with the conventional
wisdom, exit would be warranted if there signs of
emerging inflationary pressures. This danger seems
greater today in the U.S. than elsewhere.
(...)the best I can do is suggest certain scenarios. In
any event, one characteristic of complex systems is
that precise forecasting is literally impossible. In the
scenarios I sketch out, polices other than monetary
policy are taken as given. I proceed from the most
optimistic to the least optimistic outcomes
A first scenario assumes a happy ending, though
even that is not guaranteed. Suppose that significantly
faster growth does reemerge in the global economy, and that bond markets react in an ‘‘orderly’’ way.
Thus, monetary policy could begin to tighten and low
bond rates would move up only slowly. Ideally, they
would rise less than the increased nominal growth
rate, implying a gradual reduction in the burden of
debt over time. In this assumed world, current high
equity prices and tight risk spreads might seem generously
valued, but they would be fundamentally
justified by future growth prospects.
(...)If there are risks to the optimistic scenario, there are
even darker possibilities. The current, relatively slow
pattern of global growth could continue or even weaken
further. The secular factors suggested by Gordon [2016]
could contribute to this, as could the accumulating
headwinds of debt. In this case, both policy rates and
longer-term risk-free rates would be expected to stay
very low. However, in this environment, current equity
prices and narrow risk spreads will be increasingly seen
as unrealistic. Resulting sharp declines in the prices of
such financial assets are likely to catch out many
speculators and could, potentially, do further harm to
banking systems in countries already affected by the
crisis. Unaffected AMEs, where household debt and
property prices have continued to rise since 2007, might
be particularly badly hit. Banks everywhere will, in any
event, be further weakened by slow growth that raises
the number of non-performing loans. Both the demand
for and the supply of credit will remain very subdued, as
in Italy today.
In this scenario, the current low level of inflation
(in the AMEs) seems likely to decelerate further. As
noted above, while falling prices would exacerbate the
real burden of debt service, the likelihood seems small
that price decreases would be extrapolated into the
future and spending held back in anticipation. Nevertheless,
given the biases noted above (leading to
‘‘exit’’ being delayed), still more aggressive use of
monetary policy would likely be the chosen option to
respond to this slow growth, with central bank balance
sheets expanding still further.
On the one hand, further monetary expansion
might finally succeed in promoting more spending and
the expansion of the real economy. Deflationary
expectations might then be avoided. Logically, the
possibility cannot be ruled out that the tepid response
of spending to the monetary stimulus to date has been
simply due to the stimulus being too small. On the
other hand, there is also the possibility that this process
might get out of hand. Still more monetary
expansion might cause inflationary expectations to
finally ratchet sharply upward, leading to a sudden fall
in the demand for both base money and broader stocks
of money as well. While the demand for real assets
would rise, the effects on current production of significantly
higher levels of inflation are harder to predict
but could well be negative.
A sudden speeding up of the inflationary process
would be more likely in countries where both government
deficits and debts were initially very large.
Thus, governments would have to borrow but could
not get adequate private sector financing. This would
raise expectations of ‘‘fiscal dominance’’ further
eroding the private sector’s demand for government
paper. Bernholz [2006] has pointed out that such
processes, potentially leading to hyperinflation, are
not uncommon in history. Such outcomes would also
be consistent with those described in the famous
article by Sargent and Wallace [1981]. At the
moment, Japan is clearly the country to watch in this
regard. Should the Bank of Japan opt for still more
monetary stimulus, this danger would obviously
increase." (http://www.williamwhite.ca/sites/default/files/11369_2016_12_OnlinePDF.pdf)
Inga kommentarer:
Skicka en kommentar